ECG, Privatization and the National Interest

PDS

ECG, Privatization and the National Interest

 

By: J. Atsu Amegashie

August 16, 2019

 

Privatization of state-owned enterprises involves political and social concerns related to ownership and the distribution of wealth. Broad-based privatization takes the form of voucher-based programs, collective investment programs, and public share offerings.

 

Under share offerings, some firms are sold privately to a selected group of investors and/or some may be sold at public stock offerings. At the other extreme end of the spectrum, shares are widely distributed to the population, at very low prices, in voucher privatizations. As part of its transition from communism to a market economy, Czechoslovakia pioneered the concept of voucher privatizations in the early 1990s through the free distribution of vouchers of an initial value approximately equal to one-half of annual average income. Czechoslovakia’s privatization program transferred to private ownership most of industry and services and about half of the financial sector in less than three years. Six million people became shareholders in this process.

 

In 1987, the South Korean government adopted a broad-based ownership scheme for its privatization program dubbed: the “People’s Share Program” (PSP). The PSP had two key objectives: (i) redistribution to low income groups, and (ii) to distribute ownership as widely as possible. These objectives were met through the transfer of over US$8 billion of enterprise shares (minority stakes only) in seven major SOEs to the population — in particular, low income segments — through public offerings over a period of five years (1988-1992).

 

More conventional mechanisms are the public sale of shares on the stock market, either using auction sales or fixed-price sales. In the 1980s, the United Kingdom — given a well-developed capital market — followed a policy of spreading share ownership by favoring small share applications. About 96% of British Telecom’s (BT) employees bought shares of BT when it was privatized in the mid-1980s. At British Aerospace, the corresponding figure was 89% and at Cable and Wireless, it was 99%. In the South Korean program of public sales, low-income groups were eligible for significant discounts on share purchases. Malaysia used a collective investment scheme to redistribute wealth via underpriced privatization issues to the majority ethnic group that was economically underrepresented.

 

Writing on what he described as “democratic privatization”, John Moore, who was secretary to the UK Treasury from 1983 to 1986 and was in charge of the first wave of the UK’s privatization program in the 1980s, stated that: “Most revolutionary of all, we advertised on television, radio, billboards, and throughout the print media to bring each offering to the attention of the widest possible public … Without our determined policy of widening the market for shares, large-scale privatizations could hardly have succeeded. But widening the ownership of industry is an end as well as a means. Indeed, the issue of ownership lays bare the philosophical divide between those who seek to concentrate power, wealth, and decision making into the hands of the state, and those who believe in spreading them so that more and more people will have a genuine stake in the community.”

 

In his 2019 book titled “Foundations of Airport Economics and Finance,” Hans-Arthur Vogel defined privatization “… as a long-term private risk investment in terms of an equity stake, a … lease or concession agreement, or a “build, operate, and transfer” (BOT) franchise.”

 

The privatizations discussed above fall in the category of the permanent sale of state assets to the private sector. They are different from a lease or concession, which is a temporary form of privatization. Ghana chose to privatize ECG through a 20-year lease or concession. Whether it is permanent privatization or temporary privatization, the goal of a government — if it does not want to promote broad-based ownership as was the case in, for example, the UK, Czechoslovakia or South Korea — should be to maximize the proceeds from the temporary or permanent sale of the state-owned asset (i.e., ECG in this case).  In broad-based privatization programs, shares are typically underpriced, ostensibly to make them affordable to many people or to achieve populist political goals. Outlining the elements of broad-based privatization, H. Kwasi Prempeh, Executive Director of the Center for Democratic Development (CDD-Ghana), in an article on his Facebook wall stated that:

 

“… “local ownership” rules reserving a stated percentage of equity in privatisation or private-public deals to nationals must proceed, at the minimum, on the basis of: (1) a clearly written policy and legislative framework, not by means of ad hoc, selective discretion; (2) equal opportunity for all eligible, interested, and capable nationals to acquire the offered interests; (3) a credible, transparent, competitive process, free of conflicts of interests, for determining the terms of the deal and for selecting the winners, not some shadowy, opaque, backroom wheeling and dealing; (4) prompt payment for the full value of the equity participation acquired; and (5) full disclosure of the beneficial owners of the interests acquired.”

 

In some previous privatizations in Ghana, about 10% of the sale offer was reserved for employees but they were not able to take up the offer due to lack of funds (Appiah-Kubi, 2001). Perhaps because of a weak capital market, Ghana did not opt for private broad-based ownership of ECG, for example, through public share offerings. Thus, its objective should have been to maximize the proceeds from sale in a competitive tendering process. The notion that broad-based privatization programs and the maximization of sale proceeds may be two mutually-exclusive options is evidenced in a letter written in April 1982 by Geoffrey Howe, then the UK’s Chancellor of the Exchequer (Minister of Finance), in respect of a proposed sale of a state-owned enterprise:

 

“I assume that you are not suggesting here that ensuring a wide spread of holdings should be the dominant objective in the sale … there is a basic conflict between this objective and the objective of obtaining the best possible price for HMG (Her Majesty’s Government) as a vendor. I suggest that if any objective is to be dominant for the sale then it should be our desire to maximise sale proceeds, subject to only the need to sell sufficient shares to effect a transfer of the Company to the private sector.”

 

The Millennium Development Authority (MiDA), the government’s procuring entity initiated a process of competitive tendering in September 2015. But by later increasing the Ghanaian equity participation from 20% to 51% which apparently resulted in the withdrawal of four of the six shortlisted applicants in the competitive tendering process and disqualifying the BXC consortium, the government effectively opted to sole-source the 20-year concession to Manila Electric Company (Meralco). In fact, according to MiDA:  “The BXC consortium was disqualified prior to the financial evaluation.” Thus, there was no competitive bidding or procurement contest to determine how much a bidder or consortium was willing to pay for the 20-year lease of ECG’s assets. Opting for sole-sourcing was not a standard or a likely revenue-maximization strategy.

 

As part of the sole-sourcing strategy, there was/is a lease agreement between ECG and PDS. Section 4.4 (d) of the Request for Proposal states that “The Minimum Distribution Investment Commitment proposed shall be no lower than US$500 million during Agreement Year 1 through Agreement Year 5, with a minimum of US$200 million of the total US$500 million being invested during Agreement Year 1 through Agreement Year 3.”

 

Why was there not a competitive procurement in which various firms (in a consortium with Ghanaians, if necessary) bid for a 20-year lease of ECG’s assets with $500 million being the minimum price, what is known as a reserve price in an auction? Then the proceeds which would have at least been $500 million would have been given to the winner of the contest (subject to monitoring) — in the same manner as the USA’s $500 million — for investment in ECG. Under this arrangement, the winning consortium would have had to pay its bid (at least $500 million) upfront to the GoG (just as in the case of permanent privatization) and GoG would not have interfered in its internal affairs. This would not have affected the Bulk Supply Agreement under which the winning consortium has to pay ECG for the supply of power to enable ECG pay the generators of power (i.e., VRA and co) nor would it have required a bank guarantee for the lease payment. ECG’s assets would not have been transferred until the winning consortium had paid its bid in full.

 

Further Reading

Kojo Appiah-Kubi (2001). State-Owned Enterprises and Privatisation in Ghana. Journal of Modern African Studies 39: 197 – 229.

Stuart W. Bell (1995). _Sharing the wealth: privatization through broad-based ownership strategies_. WDP 285, Washington, D.C.: The World Bank.

Boycko, Maxim; Shleifer, Andrei and Vishny, Robert W. (1994). Voucher Privatization. Journal of Financial Economics, April 1994, 249–266.

John Moore (1992). British Privatization — Taking Capitalism to the People.  Harvard Business Review, January-February, 1992 issue.

David Parker (2016). The Official History of Privatisation Vol. I: The formative years 1970-1987. London and New York: Routledge

Jones, Steven L.; Megginson, William; Nash, Robert and Netter, Jeffry. (1999). Share Issue Privatizations as Financial Means to Political and Economic Ends. Journal of Financial Economics, August 1999, 217–253.

 

Atsu Amegashie is a D&D Fellow at CDD-Ghana. He is a Professor of Economics at the University of Guelph in Canada and a Fellow of the Center for Economic Studies and the Ifo Institute for Economic Research (CESifo) in Munich, Germany and the Tshepo Institute of Wilfrid Laurier University, Canada. His fields of specialization are Public Economics, Development Economics, and Microeconomics.

Facebook
Twitter
LinkedIn
WhatsApp
Email
Print

Related Articles

Afrobarometer

Instituted in 1999, Afrobarometer is a Pan-African, non-partisan survey research project that conducts...

CODEO

CDD-Ghana established the Coalition of Domestic Election Observers (CODEO) in the year 2000...

Corruption Watch

It seeks to promote integrity in public life by demanding and activating responsiveness and accountability ...

D&G Bootcamp

The overall goal is to promote and deepen democratic consolidation, good governance...

Freedom Project

The overall goal is to promote and deepen democratic consolidation, good governance...

I Am Aware

The I AM AWARE project is CDD-Ghana’s non-partisan citizen empowerment campaign..

WAEON

WAEON is an independent, non-partisan, and non-religious organization...

WAYLead Fellowship

The overall goal is to promote and deepen democratic consolidation, good governance...